A review of the new book by Joseph Stiglitz
The Independent, 23rd December 2005
If you're looking for a Christmas read to curl
up with in front of the fire, this is not the
book. This is a book for people - economics teachers,
say, or Chancellors of the Exchequer - whose hearts
don't sink at a glossary full of terms like "tariff
binding", and "Pareto efficiency".
It is, in short, hard going, but this is not surprising.
Fair Trade for All is, after all, a book by a
Nobel-prize winning economist which sets out to
tackle that knottiest of global economic problems:
the intrinsic unfairness of the global trading
framework. What is surprising - and heartening
- is that a book like this is now considered a
reasonably mainstream read.
A decade ago, before the Seattle street protests
against the World Trade Organisation (WTO) and
long before Make Poverty History, books like this
were published by academic publishers and read
by economists and the most committed of campaigners.
Today, possibly much to his own surprise, Joseph
Stiglitz is a bestseller. Not bad for a bearded
economist whose idea of a good chapter heading
is "Trade Liberalisation and the Costs of
Adjustment".
But the dryness of language and the painstaking,
evidence-based presentation favoured by Stiglitz
and Andrew Charlton should not be allowed to obscure
the power of the points they make. They set out
to produce a kind of Beveridge Report for the
21st-century economy, and to knock away some of
the shibboleths underpinning the free trade ideology
which still dominates global economic thinking.
And they largely succeed.
Not that much of what they say is actually new.
The key problem is easily grasped without a Nobel
Prize: the global trading framework which evolved
over the past 50 years has been largely stitched
up by rich countries in their own interests. Furthermore,
it has been soaked for three decades in the all-encompassing
ideology of neo-liberalism, which holds that for
all countries, at all times, the way to achieve
economic growth, and thus the betterment of the
human condition, is to remove, and to keep on
removing, barriers to trade.
This "Washington Consensus" has been
dominant since the late 1970s. Unfortunately,
as Stiglitz dryly points out, "it is difficult
to identify the evidentiary source of the bullishness
for unqualified trade liberalisation". This
is an economist's way of saying that the emperor
has no clothes; that trade liberalisation has
become a dogma that does not deliver. Indeed,
poor countries which have grown rich have done
so by doing the opposite of what the neoliberals
told them to. "To date," Stiglitz writes,
"not one successful developing country has
pursued a purely free market approach to development."
Forcing poor countries to open their markets,
in fact, often simply entrenches poverty and inequality.
What is needed, says Stiglitz, is a trading system
which focuses on poverty-reduction and fairness.
He and Charlton lay out a number of detailed
ideas, including a proposal under which all WTO
members would have to provide unfettered market
access for countries smaller and poorer than them;
a commitment by developed countries to eliminate
agricultural subsidies; the integration of environment
and human-rights measures into trade agreements;
and the removal of global agreements which favour
the rich, like those on patents and intellectual
property.
In all, they provide a workable and reasonable,
if somewhat ponderous, way to make the current
system fairer. What they don't do is live up to
the claim that they have come up with "a
radical new economic model". Stiglitz has
for some time been seen as something of a Great
White Hope by those campaigning to change the
global economic model.
He is actually a cautious, fair-minded neo-Keynesian,
with some sensible ideas. Future historians may
conclude that a society in which the ultra-reasonable
Joseph Stiglitz was seen as a radical was far
more in thrall to the gods of the market than
it could bring itself to admit.
|